Information about Sub-Saharan Africa África subsahariana
Chapter

4 Analytical Aspects of the Debt in Problems of Heavily Indebted Poor Countries

Editor(s):
Zubair Iqbal, and S. Kanbur
Published Date:
September 1997
Share
  • ShareShare
Information about Sub-Saharan Africa África subsahariana
Show Summary Details
Author(s)

After a difficult period following the onset of the debt crisis in 1982, the debt situation of most middle-income debtor countries has improved substantially. However, a group of low-income countries, most of which are in sub-Saharan Africa, has continued to experience serious difficulties in managing the servicing of their relatively high stocks of external debt.1 The various dimensions of the strategy currently adopted by the international community toward policy reform and the debt-servicing difficulties experienced by the heavily indebted poor countries have been highlighted in detail in previous work by the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank (IMF, 1995a; World Bank, 1995). Instruments used have included rescheduling, concessional refinancing, and the provision of further resources, the process being associated with close policy monitoring and conditionality.

Under London terms, and subsequently Naples terms, the approach has been supplemented by offers of partial debt-stock reduction by Paris Club creditors conditional upon the establishment of a track record of policy implementation and ongoing adjustment efforts. Given the low levels of per capita income, most HIPCs are expected to be offered conditional debt reduction by the Paris Club at a level of concessionality of 67 percent in present value terms on their eligible debt;2 post-cutoff-date debt has not been considered eligible, and no further reschedulings are presumed. The indebted country is also committed under Paris Club rescheduling to seek comparable debt relief from commercial creditors and from official bilateral creditors outside the Paris Club.3

A number of debt reduction and restructuring agreements have been reached between HIPCs and commercial creditors, a process aided by the provision of financing for such purposes from official creditors. However, in a limited number of HIPCs, matters remain to be resolved with private creditors. For official bilateral creditors outside the Paris Club, it has proved somewhat more difficult to achieve a coordinated response, in part because of valuation problems, and thus to determine what might constitute comparable treatment of claims. The multilaterals have continued to concentrate on providing financing and have not played a role in debt-stock reduction (at least with respect to their own loans), except insofar as providing concessional refinancing lowers debt in present value terms.

Creditor and debtor countries as well as the international financial institutions are currently debating whether existing initiatives are sufficient to resolve the debt problems of HIPCs and, if not, how to develop appropriate new strategies. To provide a conceptual framework within which to analyze HIPCs’ debt problems, this paper addresses some of the methodological issues underlying debt sustainability analysis and reviews the theory and empirical evidence on the effects of debt on macroeconomic performance as they apply to the specific case of HIPCs.

The debt problems of HIPCs differ in many dimensions from those of the middle-income countries that received most of the attention of economists and policymakers during the debt crisis of the 1980s. HIPCs are characterized not only by high debt, but also by relatively poor economic performance and slow economic policy reform. The links between high debt and the implementation of policy reform are thus crucial. Also, in contrast with middle-income countries, HIPCs have continued to receive a positive net transfer of resources from external creditors and donors—the median ratio of net transfers to GDP was about 11 percent on average during the 1990–94 period. In spite of these large net transfers, most HIPCs are in arrears on at least a portion of their external obligations. Finally, the creditors of HIPCs are mainly official creditors (bilateral and multilateral), as opposed to private commercial creditors. Accordingly, creditor behavior is not driven primarily by profit maximization but rather by a more complex set of goals. These considerations suggest that, to provide a useful background to the policy debate, the conventional approach for analyzing debt problems and debt reduction options needs to be adapted to accommodate the characteristics of HIPCs. This is the goal of this paper.

The material is organized as follows: the first section contains a brief overview of the structure and the recent evolution of the external debt of HIPCs. In the second section, debt sustainability analysis is discussed and the options available to creditors in case debt is judged to be unsustainable are reviewed. The third section contains a discussion of the effects of debt (and of debt reduction) on economic performance, while the fourth section reviews empirical evidence on the subject.

An Overview of the Debt Situation of HIPCs

As background to the analysis, it is useful to consider some summary information on the external debt situation of HIPCs. In all HIPCs, the external debt stock was at least twice the value of exports on average during the 1992–94 period, with several countries having ratios in excess of 1,000 percent.4 In contrast to Latin American debt, however, a sizable portion of the debt of most HIPCs was contracted on concessional terms. Because of concessionality, the face value of external debt is not a good measure of the debt burden. The ratio of the present value of future debt-service obligations to exports is a more informative indicator.5Figure 1 presents the data for most HIPCs (37) averaged for the 1992–94 period; the screened bar gives the face value of debt while the white bar shows the present value measure of debt. After concessionality is taken into account, the debt-to-exports ratio was below 200 percent for 4 countries and was between 200 and 400 percent for 20 countries. Five countries had ratios between 400 and 600 percent, and the remaining eight were above 1,000 percent; the median was 340 percent. To put these numbers in perspective, at the height of the debt crisis in the mid-1980s the comparable debt-exports ratio was about 400 percent for Mexico, 450 percent for Brazil, and 700 percent for Argentina; for non-HIPC developing countries, the ratio has averaged about 130 percent in recent years.

Figure 1.HIPCs: Debt-to-Exports Ratio and Present Value of Debt Service to Exports Ratio, 1992–94

Source: World Bank Debtor Reporting System.

Note: Because of data irregularities, Liberia, Nicaragua, Somalia, and Sudan have been excluded.

The magnitude of the indebtedness indicators in HIPCs results from the combined effect of sizable external inflows and low growth rates of output and exports during the past decade. A number of factors have been behind the relatively weak economic performance of these countries, including adverse terms of trade developments and the incidence of drought and civil war. However, deficiencies in macroeconomic management and the persistence of microeconomic distortions and structural weaknesses have also played a significant role. Although most HIPCs have had economic stabilization and structural adjustment programs supported by the IMF and the World Bank for a number of years, the pace of policy reform has remained uneven.

For HIPCs, with only one exception, debt service paid in 1993 (the most recent year for a which a full data set has been assembled) was below contractual debt service. Figure 2 shows the distribution of the number of countries by debt-service paid to debt service due by decile. This pattern has been a recurring feature of the difficulties that HIPCs have faced in managing their external debt situations in recent years. Arrears have been accumulated largely toward official bilateral creditors, although a few HIPCs have incurred relatively large arrears to commercial creditors. Rescheduling and debt restructuring by Paris Club creditors in the context of programs supported by the IMF and the World Bank have been the main instruments used to deal with the problem of HIPC arrears and to lower their contractual debt-service obligations. Most HIPCs have fully serviced their multilateral obligations, but four HIPCs (Liberia, Somalia, Sudan, and Zaïre)6 have arrears of six months or more to the World Bank and the IMF. Eight countries (the four listed above plus Central African Republic, Guinea-Bissau, Madagascar, and Niger) have arrears of six months or more with the African Development Bank.

Figure 2.Debt-Service Performance by the HIPCs, 1993

(Number of countries by decile of debt service paid to debt service due)

Source: World Bank Debtor Reporting System.

The composition by type of creditor of HIPCs’ aggregate debt (in present value terms) is shown in Figure 3.7 The total stock was $164 billion in present value terms at the end of 1994. Debt to private creditors amounted to 17 percent of the total (7 percent short term and 10 percent long term). Debt to official bilateral creditors was about 64 percent of the total, which was more or less evenly divided between Paris Club and non-Paris Club creditors. The remaining 19 percent of the total is accounted for by multilateral institutions, the distribution of which is also shown in Figure 3.

Figure 3.Debt Stock of HIPCs, 1994

Source: World Bank Debtor Reporting System.

Note: Includes only heavily indebted poor countries eligible for assistance from the International Development Association; excludes Nigeria.

It is important to note that most HIPCs have continued to receive a positive net transfer of resources from the creditor/donor community.8 The median of net transfers to HIPCs was about 11 percent of GDP on average during the 1990–94 period. This is in contrast to the situation facing the heavily indebted middle-income countries in the mid-1980s, when they were obliged to make substantial net transfers of resources to creditors. The average net transfer of resources to external creditors during the 1984–88 period, for example, was 5 percent of GDP for Mexico and more than 2 percent of GDP for Brazil and Argentina (Cohen, 1995).

Maintaining positive net resource transfers to HIPCs has required an increased commitment of resources on concessional terms by official creditors. Official bilateral creditors have made resources available more often to HIPCs on a grant basis, and they have also restructured portions of outstanding claims on concessional terms or written off portions of such claims for countries judged to be performing well. Resources from the multilateral institutions have in recent years been largely confined to loans on highly concessional terms, and these now account for the bulk of new net debt-creating flows to HIPCs.

Debt Sustainability Analysis

When creditors consider debt relief initiatives for a highly indebted country, a crucial question is whether the current debt burden is judged to be sustainable; that is, whether the country will be able in all likelihood to meet its current and future external obligations in full without resorting to rescheduling in the future or accumulations of arrears.9 In the case of HIPCs, most of which have experienced arrears and rescheduling in the recent past, the question is whether future export and output growth prospects are strong enough to bring to an end debt-servicing difficulties within a reasonable period of time.

The basic rationale for the analysis of debt sustainability scenarios arises out of consideration of national solvency. The national solvency constraint by itself imposes relatively weak conditions on the behavior of the private and public sectors and may not necessarily be a binding constraint, but it does provide a framework within which to assess a country’s ability to meet its future debt obligations.10. For example, as Buiter (1990) puts it, “… the ‘forward-looking’ accounting framework involved in solvency assessments can be used to evaluate the internal consistency of plans for external borrowing, debt service, exports, imports and other external transactions.” Nevertheless, it needs to be stressed that a considerable amount of (explicit or implicit) economic modeling is required to undertake such exercises so as to form a conditional judgment as to sustainability.

The methodology typically employed for debt sustainability calculations involves choosing a time horizon (often 10 years or even 20 years out), and projecting the growth rates of the main macroeconomic variables in the indebted country for that horizon (see, e.g., Cline, 1995). These projections, together with estimates of future voluntary inflows of foreign capital, are then used to construct the balance of payments accounts for the country. For external debt to be judged sustainable, the scenarios must satisfy two conditions. First, during the projection period, balance of payments equilibrium must be achieved without resorting to exceptional financing. Second, the level of indebtedness at the end of the period must be low enough to make future debt-service problems unlikely. The latter condition is typically evaluated by computing indebtedness indicators such as the ratio of debt to GDP, the ratio of debt to exports, or the debt-service ratio, for the last years of the projection period.

Deciding whether these ratios are sufficiently low inevitably involves the exercise of a fair amount of judgment. As noted (e.g., in IMF, 1987), it is often not possible, even after the fact, to measure the factors that would allow an accurate prediction as to what levels of the ratios would be sustainable. The chief practical value of indicators is that they signal situations in which debt-service difficulties become more likely. The rule of thumb warning sign is usually taken to be when the ratio of the present value of debt service to exports is on the order of 200–250 percent and when the ratio of debt service to exports is on the order of 20–25 percent; these figures are based on an empirical analysis of the experience of developing countries and their debt-service performance over time. For instance, Underwood (1990) ranked 111 developing countries by their ratio of debt to exports, with debt defined net of official reserves and adjusted for the degree of concessionality. With one exception, all the countries that avoided rescheduling had debt-exports ratios below 200 percent, while most countries with a history of rescheduling or interest arrears had debt-exports ratios above 200 percent. Cohen (1995) revisited the issue, and proposed an additional way of identifying the critical threshold for African debt based on the experience of Latin American countries: the maximum net transfer to creditors that these countries made during the most difficult part of the debt crisis was about 5 percent of GDP. Given the current ratio of exports to GDP for Africa and under some assumptions about the real interest rate and the future rate of growth of the African countries, similarly sized transfers would translate into a ratio of debt to exports of about 200 percent (in present value terms) and is consistent with Underwood’s findings.

Threshold debt ratios derived for developing countries in general may not be fully applicable to HIPCs because these countries are the recipients of large inflows of foreign assistance in the form of both grants and concessional loans. Hence, the debt-servicing capacity of HIPCs depends not only on their ability to generate foreign exchange through exports, but also on how much foreign assistance is expected to be forthcoming in the future. Most of these countries can expect to receive positive net transfers for the foreseeable future, and thus it is possible to argue that the ratio of debt to exports can underestimate their ability to sustain a given level of debt. It can also be argued that the expectation of the receipt of a stream of positive transfers over time for this group of countries changes the nature of possible intertemporal allocation. Thus, a judgment can be made as to the extent to which it is reasonable to bring forward debt-creating flows to the present (and hence accept higher debt stocks in present value terms now) in order to finance increased investment and consumption today.11

To construct debt sustainability scenarios, it is necessary to make assumptions about the future path of economic policy in the indebted country. Here several approaches may be adopted. One could be to project the policy stance that appears most likely to be adopted, and that may not necessarily be fully consistent with a scenario of high long-term growth. In this case, the projections would reflect the “best available forecast” of future economic performance.12 Alternatively, the scenarios may be constructed under the assumption that, to the extent judged politically and economically feasible, future policies will be aimed at enhancing output and export growth through adjustment and reform programs that will maximize the country’s long-term repayment capacity. This can be referred to as the “best policies” approach.13

Because most of the external debt of HIPCs is public debt, external debt sustainability requires that the external payments situation and the government budget should be considered alongside each other. Hence, the analysis should consider whether the government will be able, and willing, to adjust and restructure noninterest public expenditure, taxation, and domestic financing to be consistent with the size and path of the scheduled net fiscal transfers forthcoming from abroad. Thus it may be misleading to characterize a country in terms of a single representative, national agent with command over the country’s resources and to overlook the constraints and the behavioral differences and interactions between the private and public sectors.14 In addition, some governments have direct access to foreign exchange because of their control of export revenues, for example, through state oil companies, so that they are less dependent on taxing the private sector in order to obtain the domestic resources necessary to acquire the needed foreign exchange for the discharge of external debt-service obligations. Past experience with external debt crises indicates that in a significant number of countries debt problems have been due to fiscal problems and not necessarily to balance of payments difficulties (Cohen, 1988b). Also, because in several HIPCs fiscal reform and consolidation have proved difficult to achieve (World Bank, 1994), this dimension of debt sustainability needs careful evaluation.

For any particular country, debt sustainability analysis has some limitations. First, the calculations are sensitive to the projections of exogenous variables, and the margins of error are inevitably large. For instance, the balance of payments position of several HIPCs depends crucially on the behavior of commodity prices, and any significant deviation of commodity prices from the path envisioned in the projections can potentially alter the conclusions about debt sustainability. At the onset of the debt crisis in the early 1980s, some projection models reached the conclusion that Latin American countries’ debt was sustainable in part because they failed to predict the sharp drop in commodity prices that occurred in the mid-1980s (Cline, 1995). The implications of such deviations can, however, be examined by undertaking sensitivity analyses in the scenarios.

Second, debt sustainability analysis measures a country’s “ability to pay” but, as emphasized by the literature on sovereign debt pioneered by Eaton and Gersovitz (1981), debt problems may derive from a lack of “willingness to pay.” Thus an indebted government that has the necessary revenues to finance debt service may still choose to run arrears if the consequences of the default are thought to be minimal. For countries indebted to commercial creditors, default costs include reduced access to future credit and foreign investment and, possibly, to foreign markets, as well as the loss of reputation for fulfilling contractual obligations. These costs have played an important part in motivating countries to repay during the debt crisis. The literature on sovereign debt has not, however, addressed the issue of what the perceived costs of a default may be when the creditors are foreign countries (who also provide development assistance) and multilateral institutions. As indicated above, most HIPCs are servicing at least a portion of their external debt, but at the same time they are receiving large inflows of development assistance that official creditors/donors provide in a concerted effort to support the indebted country. The potential effects of a debtor’s default on the flows of foreign assistance forthcoming from official creditors are bound to be an important element in determining “willingness to pay” in HIPCs.

If a country’s debt has become so large that it cannot reasonably be expected to service the debt as scheduled, creditors must decide on how to react when the debtor goes into arrears. In some cases, the indebted country may decide that outstanding claims are so large that it makes little sense attempting to service much of the debt at all. This amounts to an explicit default on the part of the debtor, and arrears will continue to accumulate, the consequences of which depend on a multiplicity of factors (including the identity of the creditor). Creditors have to decide on the suspension of new disbursements, including for official bilateral creditors whether that should embrace halting assistance in the form of grants. If the indebted country is endeavoring to make some (more than token) debt-service payments, the creditors may decide to provide more new financing to the country, so that debt payments can be made out of the proceeds of a new loan; but such a reaction is clearly problematic if the debt sustainability analysis subsequently suggests that the debt is so high that solvency rather than liquidity is really at issue. Or a judgment can be made by creditors that reducing the outstanding obligations by forgiving part of the principal or of the interest is justified. Interest rate reduction can also be done indirectly, by means of a commitment to refinance old loans by means of new loans at lower interest rates.

If the last course of action is chosen and relief on part of the debt is granted, the creditors lose the residual recovery value on part of their claims: if, contrary to expectations, the debtor’s economic performance happens to improve to a degree that restores solvency (or willingness to pay), the creditors will have no right to demand full payment. Conversely, if the country was in arrears or if the refinancing alternative had been pursued, then the creditors would receive a higher debt-service payment. Of course, the more sustainable the external debt position of the country appears to be, the larger is the creditors’ residual recovery value on part of their claims, and the larger is the cost of explicit debt reduction relative to other courses of action. Decisions by Paris Club creditors to offer partial and conditional debt reduction under London terms and subsequently under Naples terms can be interpreted partly as reflecting a judgment that the stock of debt out-standing for many HIPCs was unsustainable and the residual recovery value on some part of the debt minimum (at least relative to the potential benefits from debt forgiveness).

It should also be noted that the up-front accounting loss resulting from a debt-reduction operation is likely to be much larger than the economic loss if the loan is still kept at face value or is otherwise over-valued on the creditors’ books, and adequate or realistic loan-loss provisions have not been set aside. In practice, some creditors may be reluctant to grant debt forgiveness because they are unwilling or unable to take a large accounting loss. Also, explicit debt reduction may expose the extent of past imprudent lending decisions with adverse effects on the reputation of the creditor vis-à-vis borrowers and financial markets. In this case, the ability to refinance nonperforming loans, thereby concealing the losses, may create a moral hazard problem on the creditor side. In private commercial banking, regulatory limits on banks’ exposure toward individual borrowers therefore constrain the use of the refinancing strategy.

If creditors deal with a situation in which debt has become unsustainable by granting debt relief through some debt reduction or ongoing refinancing, then the debtor is not formally in default, and creditors consent to accept a different schedule or different amounts of debt-service payments than called for in the original loan contracts. Hence, if this action is interpreted as a sign that creditors are soft on debtors who do not pay, it may create moral hazard problems: the country in question may consider that further significant deviations from contractual obligations in the future will also be tolerated, and other debtors may form the same opinion and follow suit as well. (The issue of moral hazard is discussed further in the next section.)

It also needs to be borne in mind that there are limits on the extent to which it may be judged appropriate to grant debt relief by reducing the level (in present value terms) of a country’s external debt. The fact that a country has entered into loan contracts carries with it an obligation to make bona fide efforts to service such contracts, and this implies servicing debt up to the limit reasonably judged to be sustainable. While such judgments are difficult to make, for creditors to do more than this (by reducing outstanding claims still further) so as, for example, to make room for a larger volume of new loans would be incompatible with the nature of the loan contracts entered into and would be dynamically inconsistent; furthermore, if fresh loans (rather than grants) were to continue over time, it would only make sense to the extent that such new loans were expected to be accompanied by growth in the indebted country’s debt-servicing capacity.

Debt and Economic Performance: Theory

At the center of the HIPC external debt problem is the question of whether the large debt burden is one of the factors contributing to weak economic performance and the uneven pace of economic reform in these countries. Although the need to service external debt can be expected to reduce growth and investment—provided future access to external resources is unaffected—the question is whether the adverse effects may be of a sufficient magnitude to justify increased explicit debt reduction beyond the presently available mechanisms. This section reviews the insights that economic theory has to offer on the relationship between debt burden and economic performance.

The Debt Overhang Theory

The main theoretical argument in support of explicit debt reduction, as opposed to continued flow rescheduling, is the debt overhang theory. The theory is based on the premise that, if debt will exceed the country’s repayment ability with some probability in the future, expected debt service is likely to be an increasing function of the country’s output level. Thus some of the returns from investing in the domestic economy are effectively “taxed away” by existing foreign creditors, and investment by domestic and new foreign investors is discouraged. According to the theory, a reduction in the face value of future debt obligations will reduce the distortion due to the implicit tax, and this will increase investment (see, e.g., Krugman, 1988). Since debt reduction leads to increased investment and repayment capacity, the portion of the debt that remains outstanding becomes more likely to be repaid. If this effect is strong enough, then debt reduction may benefit the creditors as well as the debtor, and the debtor is said to be on the wrong side of the debt Laffer curve.15 If the debtor is on the right side of the Laffer curve, debt reduction may still be a positive-sum game, but creditors need to receive some compensation, perhaps in the form of enhancements that increase the value of the remaining debt. This essentially is the approach to debt reduction used in the Brady Plan deals.16

The debt overhang theory was originally formulated for countries heavily indebted to private commercial creditors. HIPCs, however, are mostly indebted to official creditors, and they also receive substantial transfers (often in the form of concessional assistance from some of their creditors). If creditors allocate foreign assistance independently of the size of debt-related flows, then the standard debt overhang theory would apply equally to HIPCs. If the foreign assistance is related to the debt and debt service of HIPCs, whether and how a debt overhang may create adverse incentive effects for economic performance is a more complex question. The answer depends on the criteria by which foreign assistance flows are determined. For instance, creditors may reduce foreign assistance to countries whose economic conditions improve. In this case, incentives to undertake growth-enhancing activities are weakened, but this is true regardless of the size of external debt. However, if, in addition, heavily indebted countries are more likely to be dependent on foreign assistance in the future, then the adverse incentive effects are worse for these countries. Conversely, if foreign assistance tends to be provided as growth-enhancing policies are undertaken, then the debt overhang effects would tend to be weakened.

In its original formulation, the debt overhang theory centered on the adverse effects of debt on investment in physical capital. The scope of the theory, however, is much broader. To the extent that foreign creditors are expected to appropriate some of the benefits of future growth, any activity that involves incurring costs up front for the sake of increased output in the future will be discouraged (Corden, 1989). Such activities may include investment in human capital and in technology acquisition, whose effects on growth may be even stronger over time in HIPCs than the effect of investment in physical capital. Also, the implementation of extensive economic reforms, such as trade liberalization, privatization, or fiscal reform, may entail incurring an immediate cost (political as well as economic), while the benefits will materialize only in the future. If policymakers expect foreign creditors to appropriate most of the gains from policy reform through larger debt-service payments, then the presence of a debt overhang may be a strong obstacle to economic reform.17 This potential effect is of particular concern in HIPCs, where the extent of microeconomic distortions and poor macroeconomic management is often such that widespread policy reform is a prerequisite for sustained and stable growth (World Bank, 1994).

Because HIPC external debt is mostly a liability of the government, strictly speaking the overhang effects outlined above should only affect actions under direct government control, that is, public investment or policy reform. How a debt overhang discourages private investment depends on how the government is expected to raise the fiscal revenue necessary to finance external debt service.18 For instance, if the government is expected to resort to the inflation tax or to a capital levy, private investment is likely to be discouraged.19 If revenue will be raised through an export tax, then investment in the export-oriented sector will be depressed.

Other Effects of Debt on Economic Performance

The debt overhang effect is only one of the channels through which the need to service a large amount of external obligations can affect economic performance. Other channels may prove to be equally important. These include the crowding-out effect, the lack of access to international financial markets, and the effects of the stock of debt on the general level of uncertainty in the economy.

The debt overhang theory implies that a reduction in future debt service should lead to an increase in current investment. A perhaps stronger case can be made that a reduction in current debt service should lead to an increase in current investment for any given level of future indebtedness. This is because the smaller debt service is, the more resources are available to finance investment without reducing consumption; hence, the utility cost of financing investment should be smaller, and more investment should be carried out. Cohen (1993) has dubbed this effect the crowding-out effect of debt on investment.20 While the debt overhang effect clearly implies that a strategy of debt reduction is better than one of ongoing rescheduling combined with new resource inflows, this is not the case for the crowding-out effect. If there is no debt overhang, then an identical increase in investment could be obtained by giving the country a new loan instead of reducing current debt service, since a new loan would be just as effective at crowding in investment.21 So being able to distinguish empirically between the two effects has important consequences for the design of a strategy for HIPCs’ debt problems.

Several authors have noted that the developing countries involved in the debt crisis of the 1980s, having lost access to world financial markets, experienced a sharp increase in their shadow cost of capital, which greatly contributed to the decline in investment and output.22 A major benefit of debt-reduction operations in middle-income countries has been to restore access to international financial markets and to encourage the repatriation of flight capital. While the inflows of “involuntary” new money in the rescheduling period of middle-income countries (1983–89) went to the indebted country government, the capital inflows of the early 1990s were directed primarily to the private sector. Presumably, this led to a better allocation of resources and a more efficient selection of investment projects. Hence, a potential benefit of a strategy of debt reduction relative to one of ongoing refinancing is that debt reduction may help strengthen the private sector in the indebted countries. However, because some HIPCs would be unlikely to attract much foreign private capital even after receiving some external debt reduction, this argument may be less relevant than in the case of middle-income countries.

Another argument that is sometimes made to support explicit debt reduction is that with ongoing rescheduling there is considerable uncertainty as to what fraction of scheduled debt payments will be serviced from the country’s own resources. This amount is—implicitly or explicitly—the subject of ongoing negotiations between the authorities in the indebted country and the various categories of creditors, the outcome of which depends on complex factors, including changes in foreign aid budgets in creditor countries, political developments, and so on. Such uncertainty may contribute to generating instability in the indebted economy, thereby discouraging domestic investment (see, e.g., Claessens, Oks, and van Wijnbergen, 1993).

Debt Reduction, Moral Hazard, and Conditionality

As pointed out above, when the long-run creditor-debtor relationship is considered, either a strategy of explicit debt reduction or one of ongoing flow rescheduling or de facto rollovers through new loans may create moral hazard problems. Specifically, having found creditors willing to accept a change in scheduled debt service today, the debtor (and other debtors) may form the belief that creditors have eased their position, and that more debt will be either forgiven or rolled over in the future as long as the country’s repayment prospects remain clouded. This reasoning, of course, may lead to a reduction in efforts to service the debt in the future.

To limit moral hazard, creditors have found it necessary to apply conditionality to the refinancing and rescheduling process. Thus, resources are disbursed period by period while the country policy stance is closely monitored by the IMF and the World Bank, a process dubbed by some observers (e.g., Williamson, 1988) as the short-leash approach. If debt relief is provided through explicit debt reduction, the impact of moral hazard can be lessened if creditors offer debt reduction only to countries that have established a track record of responsible policies, and whose current debt difficulties, therefore, are largely outside the control of policymakers. This is the type of approach taken by the Paris Club in determining eligibility for stock-of-debt operations under Naples terms (see IMF, 1995a).

A potential advantage of refinancing/rescheduling (accompanied by conditionality) relative to explicit up-front debt reduction may be that allowing the IMF and the World Bank to constantly monitor policy performance in the indebted country leads to better policies and fewer moral hazard problems. With a strategy of granting debt reduction after a good track record is established, however, multilateral creditors may lose their ability to influence policy after the initial period.

If there are reasons to believe that economic reforms and sound macroeconomic policies become self-sustaining after the initial obstacles are overcome, then losing the short leash may not have much of an impact. Yet a strategy of explicit debt reduction would reduce the costs of constant negotiations and policy monitoring. In HIPCs, where the strength and depth of the professional cadre is limited, these costs are likely to be substantial (Killick, 1993; Martin, 1991). Also, the continual negotiations and performance evaluation implied by the short-leash approach may increase uncertainty about the extent of future resource flows between the indebted country and official creditors, as these flows become a function not only of budgetary and political developments in creditor countries, but of whether the authorities in the indebted country will be deemed to have maintained a sufficient degree of compliance with the policy programs.

Some authors have also criticized the short-leash approach (and policy conditionality in general) because it impedes local “ownership” of reform programs (e.g., Berg, 1991; Killick, 1994): because the conditions and substance of reform programs may be seen as being imposed from outside, policymakers may have difficulties implementing the programs because they or other agents are not convinced that the actions being required are in the country’s own long-term interest.23 This criticism is closely related to the existence of adverse incentives for undertaking policy reform in the presence of a large debt overhang: if authorities in the indebted country perceive external creditors to be the main beneficiaries of the reforms, then ownership will be weak, and program implementation will be difficult.24

It should be emphasized, however, that to the extent that the HIPCs will continue to receive official resources in the form of concessional loans (e.g., ESAF and IDA resources) or bilateral grants even after their external debt is reduced, then these countries would still be subject to conditionality and their policies would continue to be scrutinized by the IMF and the World Bank. The major benefit from abandoning the short leash, then, would be to put an end to the process of applying conditionality to the rescheduling and rollovers of old debt obligations.

Finally, for the short-leash approach to be effective, it is crucial that the creditors’ or donors’ threat of suspending new inflows when policy goes off track be credible (see, e.g., the analysis in Mosley, Harrigan, and Toye, 1995). Hence, the resolve of the official donor/creditor community as a whole to suspend disbursements when a country fails to comply with performance criteria is a necessary element for an effective strategy to address HIPC debt problems. The World Bank (1994) looked at the relationship between change in net external transfers per capita and change in macroeconomic policies in the 1980s in sub-Saharan Africa. This study found that countries that benefited from increased transfers between 1981–86 and 1987–91 were almost equally split between those whose macroeconomic policies improved and those whose policies deteriorated. A recent assessment by the IMF on ESAF arrangements (IMF, 1995a) concluded that transfers from official creditors/donors have generally rewarded those HIPCs making stronger policy adjustment efforts, although it noted that, while progress had been made, the achievement of external viability was still in question and that growth remained somewhat below that judged feasible in a number of countries.

It should also be noted that, if one of the shortcomings of the current debt strategy is thought to be the difficulty in applying credible policy conditionality, then the appropriate solution would be to create the conditions for a more effective implementation of IMF and World Bank programs in HIPCs. Unless strong incentives to pursue appropriate policies are created, additional debt reduction would not bring to an end HIPCs’ debt problems but would simply be followed by more rescheduling and rollovers in the future.

Debt and Economic Performance: Evidence

The previous section showed that theoretical analysis yields a number of hypotheses on the impact of debt on economic performance. Implied by these hypotheses are alternative approaches to debt relief—debt reduction up front or after a track record is established, ongoing rescheduling or writedowns with conditionality, and so on. It would be important to assess the evidence on the various hypotheses as the basis for forming a judgment on the appropriate policy response to the debt problem both of HIPCs in general and also of individual countries. This section considers two types of evidence available in the literature: that on the relationship between debt and investment, and evidence on the impact of the Brady Plan in middle-income countries.

Debt and Investment

There is a large literature on the determinants of growth and investment in developing countries. Although none of the studies focuses exclusively on HIPCs, a number of them include HIPCs in the sample.25 Most econometric studies include a fairly standard set of domestic, external, policy, and exogenous explanatory variables. Some of these studies have also included debt variables. Not surprisingly, almost all such studies find one or more debt variables to be significantly and negatively correlated with investment or growth (depending on the focus of the study). While this evidence provides prima facie support for the argument that debt and economic performance are negatively related, it still leaves open the two key questions: the relative importance of debt vis-à-vis other factors; and the channels of the adverse impact of debt.

While most studies include key exogenous and policy variables, such as indicators of (the disequilibrium of) the exchange rate, the degree of openness of the economy, fiscal balance, or the domestic real interest rate, the question arises whether these sufficiently control for country circumstances and, if not, whether the debt variables pick up the effect of some other, omitted exogenous or policy factors or whether there are feedback effects to other variables that mask the effects of the high levels of external debt. By nature of econometric estimation, this question cannot be resolved definitively. In an analysis of the relationship between growth and investment and debt burdens in HIPCs, IMF (1995b) also concludes that it is difficult to disentangle the role of debt overhang from other factors. Several studies, however, have found that debt variables have statistically significant negative relationships with subsequent investment or performance, even after controlling for other, contemporaneous factors. This provides a relatively robust indication of the negative effect of debt on economic performance. Furthermore, the theoretical analysis indicates that the debt burden can negatively affect some of the control variables themselves. For example, debt can affect the domestic real interest rate. Because investment is also affected by the real interest rate, the impact of debt on investment is likely underestimated when the real interest rate is also included in the regression.

The second difficulty relates to the two channels through which debt variables can affect growth or investment: one is a pure debt overhang effect; the second refers to a crowding-out effect. Most studies of investment equations generally do not distinguish between the crowding-out and the overhang effect, and the mere statistical significance of debt variables is then also not sufficient to isolate the importance of the debt overhang. To distinguish between the two effects, both the contemporaneous debt service and a variable capturing the burden of future debt service (such as the debt stock or the present value of future debt service) should be included in the regression analysis.

Greene and Villanueva (1991) and Savvides (1992) are examples of studies of investments in developing countries that include both variables as separate determinants. Greene and Villanueva find evidence of an overhang effect, but their sample of developing countries does not include any HIPCs. Conversely, for a large sample of developing countries including some HIPCs, Savvides (1992) finds that, while debt service crowded out investment, the ratio of debt to GNP had a negative but insignificant coefficient, indicating that the hypothesis of no debt overhang effects could not be rejected. These results, however, should be viewed with caution, because the studies do not correct their overhang variable (the ratio of the stock of debt to GDP or to exports) for the degree of concessionality of the loans. Hence, the measure of indebtedness used does not accurately reflect differences in the burden of future debt service across countries. Also, Greene and Villanueva (1991) include the real interest rate as a regress or, which is possibly related to the debt burden through both an overhang and a crowding-out effect For middle-income countries, Warner (1992) and Cohen (1993) use a more indirect way to attempt to identify the effect of the 1980s debt crisis on investment. They estimate investment equations before the debt crisis and assess their predictive power during the period of the crisis. Warner (1992) concludes that the debt crisis did not depress investment, while Cohen (1993) concludes that it was the crowding-out effect of current debt servicing that was significant.

One other approach to identifying the pure debt overhang effect is to estimate the debt Laffer curve through secondary market debt prices. Claessens (1990) finds that out of 29 middle-income countries, 5 were on the wrong side of the Laffer curve, suggesting that partial debt reduction would increase the expected repayment to the creditors. Claessens and others (1991) find, depending on the exact specification of their model, that 6–15 out of 35 countries were on the wrong side of the debt Laffer curve. In both papers, only extremely indebted countries were on the wrong side of the curve. Cohen (1990) does not find econometric support for the proposition that reducing the nominal value of debt would increase its market value. However, studies using secondary market prices to measure debt overhang raise issues of interpretation: an explicit reduction in the face value of debt may have little effect on the secondary market prices, not because there is no debt overhang, but because market participants expect some debt reduction to occur, and that expectation is built into the price. Finally, the relevance of this evidence for HIPCs is only marginal since secondary market prices are only available for commercial debt and most of HIPCs’ debt is official.

Impact of the Brady Plan

The Brady Plan, first put forward in 1989, involved a concerted debt relief package where commercial banks could choose from a menu of new money and debt-stock reduction options, implemented within a framework of policy conditionality. In practice, few commercial banks were willing to lend new money, and the Brady Plan has largely been debt reduction, with commercial debt stocks on average reduced by 45 percent (IMF, 1995a). The Brady Plan countries thus provide useful case studies of the effects of debt reduction on economic performance and capital flows. However, as the Brady Plan was concerned with middle-income countries mainly indebted to commercial creditors, the evidence may have limited relevance for HIPCs. There have been several studies of the early Brady deal. Two general conclusions emerge. One is the central role of macroeconomic stabilization in economic reforms undertaken before debt reduction. And second, the main channel through which the debt reduction affects growth is through a reduction in uncertainty; the reduction in future transfers appears to matter less.

Berthelemy and Vourc’h (1994) evaluate the impact of the Mexico Brady deal. They use a calibrated simulation model focusing on three key prices: the domestic interest rate, the price of debt on the secondary market, and the real exchange rate. They conclude that the Brady Plan speeded up recovery and dispelled the uncertainties that were weighing on the success of the new economic reform program at the beginning of 1989. They also conclude that if Mexico had not corrected its fiscal and macroeconomic imbalances prior to the deal, the debt relief obtained would not have been sufficient to restore a recovery of growth and creditworthiness. Oks and van Wijnbergen (1994) and Claessens, Oks, and van Wijnbergen (1993) come to similar conclusions in their analysis of the impact of the Brady deal in Mexico, highlighting the role of uncertainty. They conclude that the impact of the Brady deal came not primarily through a reduction in external transfers (either current or future) but through the fact that the deal removed uncertainty associated with continual ongoing reschedulings.

These conclusions are further confirmed by IMF (1995b), which investigates the behavior of private investment in eight, both low- and middle-income, countries (Bangladesh, Chile, Ghana, India, Mexico, Morocco, Senegal, and Thailand). Although no independent debt overhang effect on investment was identified, the study concludes that indirect evidence suggests that an earlier resolution of these countries’ debt burden would have yielded a faster rebound in investment through both the effect of a reduction in uncertainty and the lowering of country-risk premiums and interest rates.

IMF (1992–95), World Bank (1993), Cline (1995), and Fernandez-Arias (1993), among others, review the consequences of Brady agreements for other countries (Argentina, Brazil, Venezuela, etc.). These papers’ findings are that secondary market prices for debt rose generally Cline, for example, noted that the country-risk spread for Argentina fell sharply after the deal in April 1993. Similarly, there was a sharp turnaround in private capital flows to most countries, typically around the time of the Brady agreement. This happened in Venezuela in 1990, but by 1992 private flows to Venezuela fell off again after policy slippages—showing once again the importance of a sound policy framework for debt reduction to have a positive impact on private capital flows, investment, and growth.

The experience with the Brady Plan suggests that an important benefit of concerted debt reduction may be to bolster confidence in the process of policy reform undertaken by the authorities in the indebted country: from this perspective, the willingness of commercial creditors to grant debt reduction is viewed by foreign investors as an “endorsement” by the international financial community that the country is successfully pursuing sound macroeconomic policies and structural reform. This endorsement opens the way for renewed foreign capital inflows that stimulate growth. These considerations suggest that offers of increased debt relief for HIPCs may only have positive effects on economic performance observed in the case of the Brady deals if they are interpreted by international investors as an endorsement of a strong and effective program of economic stabilization and reform.

Concluding Remarks

The analytical arguments reviewed in this paper on the links between debt and economic performance have implications for whether or not consideration should be given to more debt reduction for HIPCs over and above that provided for under current mechanisms. Ongoing refinancing with conditionality, as opposed to up-front debt reduction, reduces moral hazard and provides countries with incentives to maintain good policies. But, at the same time, this short-leash approach has transaction costs, can create uncertainty, and can impede local ownership of reform programs. Up-front debt reduction may create moral hazard problems, and may weaken the incentives for maintaining sound policy. But there are theoretical arguments relating to a debt overhang as to why a high level of debt can impede investment and policy reform, since the potential returns from these may be expected to be taxed away to repay creditors.

A number of econometric studies, based mainly on the experience of middle-income highly indebted countries, find that investment is negatively correlated with external debt variables. A few have found similar effects for African countries. While suggestive, these results need to be treated with caution: debt variables may be picking up the influence of other factors, or vice versa, and most studies do not distinguish between debt-stock and debt-servicing effects. From a different perspective, some researchers have found that Brady Plan debt operations for certain middle-income countries have had beneficial effects on economic performance—principally by reducing uncertainty—but only when preceded by a period of strong policy reforms. In sum, while the hypothesis that HIPCs suffer from significant adverse effects from overhangs of debt is inconclusive, evidence from the middle-in come countries does suggest that high levels of external debt may act as a constraint on investment and growth, and that debt reduction can have beneficial effects if the policy environment is right.

In conclusion, the general analytical arguments reviewed in this paper highlight the key issues that arise in any assessment of proposals for further debt reduction beyond what is embodied in existing mechanisms. And, if further debt reduction is to be considered, this would require detailed quantitative analysis for the countries in question, to arrive at a judgment as to the balance of the different forces at play.

References

    BergE.1991“Comment,” in Restructuring Economies in Distress,ed. by V.ThomasA.ChibberM.Dailami and J.de Melo (New York: Oxford University Press).

    BerthelemyJ.-C and A.Vourc’h1994Debt Relief and Growth Development Centre Studies (Paris: OECD).

    BorenszteinE.1990a“Debt Overhang, Credit Rationing, and Investment,”journal of Development EconomicsVol. 32No. 2pp. 31535.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    BorenszteinE.1990bDebt Overhang Debt Reduction and Investment: The Case of the PhilippinesIMF Working Paper No. 90/77 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    BuiterW.1990“Some Thoughts on the Role of Fiscal Policy in Stabilization and Structural Adjustment in Developing Countries” inW. M.BuiterPrinciples of Budgetary and Financial Policy (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    ClaessensS.1990“The Debt Laffer Curve: Some Estimates” World DevelopmentVol. 18 (December) pp. 167177.

    ClaessensS.I.DiwanK.Froot and P.Krugman1991“Market-Based Debt Reduction: Principles and Prospects” Country Economics Department Policy and Research Series No. 16 (Washington:World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    ClaessensS.D.Oks and S.van Wijnbergen1993“Interest Rates, Growth, and External Debt: The Macroeconomic Impact of Mexico’s Brady Deal,”Policy Research Working Paper No. 1147 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    ClineW1995International Debt Reexamined (Washington: Institute for International Economics).

    CohenD.1988a“Is the Discount on the Secondary Market a Case for LDC Debt Relief?”Policy Research Working Paper No. 132 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    CohenD.1988b“The Management of Developing Countries’ Debt: Guidelines and Applications to Brazil,”World Bank Economic ReviewVol. 2No. 1pp. 77104.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    CohenD.1990“Debt Relief: Implications of Secondary Market Discounts and Debt Overhangs,”World Bank Economic ReviewVol. 4No. 1pp. 4353.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    CohenD.1993“Low Investment and Large LDC Debt in the 1980s,”American Economic ReviewVol. 83No. 3 (June) pp. 43749.

    CohenD.1995“The Sustainability of African Debt” (Paris: École Normale Supérieure).

    CordenW. M.1989“Debt Relief and Adjustment Incentives” in Analytical Issues in Debted. by J. A.FrenkelM. P.Dooley and P.Wickham (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    DetragiacheE.1992“The Simple Dynamics of a Debt Crisis,”journal of International Money and FinanceVol. 11 (December) pp. 55266.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    EatonJ. and R.Fernandez1995“Sovereign Debt” Handbook of International EconomicsVol. 3ed. by G. M.Grossman and K.Rogoff (Amsterdam: North Holland).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    EatonJ. and R.Fernandez and M.Gersovitz1981“Debt with Potential Repudiation: Theoretical and Empirical Analysis,”Review of Economic StudiesVol. 48pp. 284309.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    Fernandez-AriasE.1993“The Cost and Benefits of Debt Reduction,”Policy Research Working Paper No. 1169 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    GreeneJ. and D.Villanueva1991“Private Investment in Developing Countries,”Staff PapersInternational Monetary FundVol. 38No. 1 (March) pp. 3358.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    HadjimichaelM.DhaneshwarGhuraMartinMühleisenRogerNord and E. MuratUçer1995Sub-Saharan Africa: Growth Savings and Investment 1986–93IMF Occasional Paper No. 118 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    IMF1987Theoretical Aspects of the Design of Fund-Supported Adjustment Programs IMF Occasional Paper No. 55 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    IMF1995aOfficial Financing for Developing Countries World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    IMF1995b“The Response of Investment and Growth to Adjustment Policies: Lessons from Eight Countries” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary FundSeptember).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    IMF various yearsPrivate Market Financing for Developing Countries World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    JenkinsC1995“Determinants of Private Investment in Zimbabwe” (Oxford: Center for the Study of African EconomiesNovember).

    JohnsonJ.M. and S.S.Wasty1993Borrower Ownership of Adjustment Programs and the Political Economy of Reform Discussion Paper No. 199 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    KillickT.1993“Enhancing the Cost Effectiveness of Africa’s Negotiations with Its Creditors,” inInternational Monetary and Financial Issues for the 1990s Research Papers for the Group of Twenty-FourVol. 3 (Geneva: UNCTAD).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    KillickT.1994“Conditionally and the Adjustment-Development Connection,”paper presented at a conference on Fifty Years After Bretton Woods: The Future of the IMF and the World Bank MadridOctober.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    KrugmanP.1988“Financing vs. Forgiving a Debt Overhang,”Journal of Development EconomicsVol. 29pp. 25368.

    MartinM.1991The Crumbling Facade of African Debt Negotiations (New York: Macmillan).

    MlamboK. and M. C.Mhlophe1995“Investment Behavior Under Uncertainty: An Analysis of the Determinants of Investment in Zimbabwe,”paper presented to the African Economic Research Consortium Workshop JohannesburgMay.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    MosleyP.J.Harrigan and J.Toye1995Aid and Power: The World Bank and Policy-Based Lending (New York: Routledge2nd ed.).

    OksD. and S.van Wijnbergen1994“Mexico After the Debt Crisis: Is Growth Sustainable?” Latin America and Caribbean Country Deptartment II (Washington:World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    Operations Evaluation Department1992World Bank Structural and Sectoral Adjustment Operations: The Second OED Review OED Report No. 10870 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    OshikoyaT.1994“Macroeconomic Determinants of Domestic Private Investment in Africa: An Empirical Analysis,”Economic Development and Cultural ChangeVol. 42No. 3pp. 57396.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    SavvidesA.1992“Investment Slowdown in Developing Countries During the 1980s: Debt Overhang or Foreign Capital Inflows,”KyklosVol. 45 pp. 36378.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    ServenL. and A.Solimano1991“Adjustment Policies and Investment Performance in Developing Countries: Theory, Country Experiences, and Policy Implications,”Policy Research Working Paper No. 606 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    UnderwoodJ.1990“The Sustainability of International Debt” (unpublished; Washington: World Bank).

    WarnerA. M.1992“Did the Debt Crisis Cause the Investment Crisis?”Quarterly Journal of EconomicsVol. 107 (November) pp. 116186.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    WarnerA. M.1994“Mexico’s Investment Collapse: Debt or Oil?”Journal of International Money and FinanceVol. 13No. 2pp. 23956.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    WilliamsonJ.1988Voluntary Approaches to Debt Relief Policy Analyses in International Economics No. 25 (Washington: Institute for International EconomicsSeptember).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

    World Bank1994Adjustment in Africa: Reforms Results and the Road Ahead (New York:Oxford University Press).

    World Bank various yearsWorld Debt Tables: External Finance for Developing Countries (Washington:World Bank).

The authors received very helpful comments from Masood Ahmed, Michael Bruno, Ishak Diwan, Fred Jensen, Nawal Kamel, Jeffrey Katz, Homi Kharas, Fred Kilby, Malvina Pollock, Enrique Rueda-Sabater, Paolo Vieira da Cunha, and Ning Zhu of the World Bank, and from Mark Allen, Anthony Boote, Eduardo Borensztein, Stanley Fischer, Rick Haas, Mohsin Khan, and Michael Mussa of the International Monetary Fund. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the institutions with which they are affiliated.
1This group, referred to as the heavily indebted poor countries (HIPCs), includes 41 countries, of which 32 are classified as severely indebted low-income countries (SILICs) according to the World Debt Tables, 1994–95 classification. An additional 7 have received concessional treatment from the Paris Club, and 2 are lower-middle-income countries that have recently become IDA-only countries (Angola and Congo). The countries covered are Angola, Benin, Bolivia, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, Central African Republic, Chad, Congo, Côte d’Ivoire, Equatorial Guinea, Ethiopia, Ghana, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Guyana, Honduras, Kenya, Lao People’s Democratic Republic, Liberia, Madagascar, Mali, Mauritania, Mozambique, Myanmar, Nicaragua, Niger, Nigeria, Rwanda, Sao Tome and Principe, Senegal, Sierra Leone, Somalia, Sudan, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Vietnam, Republic of Yemen, Zaire, and Zambia. (In May 1997, the official name of Zaire was changed to Democratic Republic of the Congo.)
2Countries with a per capita income of more than $500 and an overall indebtedness ratio of less than 350 percent of exports in present value terms may receive a 50 percent level of concessionality on a case-by-case basis.
3The major bilateral creditors outside the Paris Club are Russia, China, and the Arab countries, including Kuwait, the Libyan Arab Jamahiriya, and Saudi Arabia. In some instances, notably the claims of Russia, the valuation of non–Paris Club creditor claims has been the subject of dispute between creditors and debtors, reflecting, among other things, differences on the appropriate exchange rate to use in valuation.
4The data are from World Bank (various years).
5The measure takes into account both the profile of debt-service payments and the concessionality of the debt structure by discounting the stream of debt-service payments.
6In May 1997, the official name of Zaïre was changed to Democratic Republic of the Congo.
7The aggregate data cover IDA-only HIPCs, thereby excluding Nigeria. Nigeria’s large size relative to the other HIPCs would distort the aggregate picture.
8The net transfer of resources from such creditors is defined as grants plus new loan disbursements minus actual interest payments and amortization of principal.
9This type of analysis obviously cannot answer the question of whether the burden of debt service is excessive according to some welfare criterion. Such a judgment is not a matter of positive economics; see, for example, Williamson (1988).
10The national solvency condition looks forward into the indefinite future and requires assumptions about the evolution of the trade balance (on goods and nonfactor services) over time. Deficits can be run for extended periods of time, provided surpluses sufficient to repay existing debt plus interest are generated at some stage. See, for example, Eaton and Fernandez (1995).
11In other words, this is a question of “aid now” versus “aid later,” and embraces the issue of to what extent future aid flows should be encumbered for the sake of being able to use the resources today.
12This type of approach has been taken in determining whether certain European countries are likely under a continuation of present policies to meet the fiscal criteria set out in the Maastricht Treaty.
13As discussed in the next section, the debt overhang theory suggests that the presence of a large stock of debt may deter the adoption of policies that maximize future repayment capacity. If that theory has empirical relevance, then choosing a “best policies” approach in debt sustainability analysis could be problematic.
14Just as national solvency considerations lie behind the forward-looking external accounting framework, so do fiscal solvency considerations lie behind intertemporal analysis of the fiscal accounts.
15The debt Laffer curve graphs expected repayment as a function of the face value of debt service. Along the right side of the curve, an increase in the face value of debt service leads to an increase in repayment, while along the wrong side of the curve increases in the face value of the debt reduce expected repayment.
16Even if it benefits creditors as a group, debt reduction may be difficult to achieve because each creditor has an incentive to free-ride. The concerted approach adopted in the Brady deals was designed to get around the free-rider problem.
17It could also be argued that, to some extent, the assistance provided by foreign creditors/donors slows down the pace of reform. Without this external assistance, some countries might be obliged to reform much faster, albeit at a higher cost.
18To the degree that private and public investment are complementary, debt overhang that leads to cuts in public investment would reduce private investment independently of tax considerations.
19Hadjimichael and others (1995) find that inflation has a significant and negative impact on private investment in sub-Saharan Africa.
20For this effect to be at work, the country must have imperfect access to world capital markets, which is certainly the case for HIPCs; the argument also assumes that the way in which debt service is reduced does not affect access to new official assistance.
21Of course, in the extreme case in which creditors always provide sufficient new money to cover debt repayment so that the need to service more debt does not result in a larger net transfer to creditors, investment would not be crowded out at all.
22See Detragiache (1992) for a theoretical model, and Borensztein (1990a) for numerical simulations indicating that this effect is large. Also, Cohen (1993) points out that, to assess whether debt played a role in reducing investment in developing countries, the investment levels of the 1980s should be compared with those of the 1960s, and not with investment in the 1970s, when developing countries temporarily enjoyed relatively easy access to world financial markets.
23Evidence on ownership and its consequences is to be found in various reviews of World Bank adjustment loans conducted by its Operations Evaluation Department. One study (Operations Evaluation Department, 1992) attempted to quantify the relationship using a methodology developed by Johnson and Wasty (1993). On the basis of a review of program audit reports, 81 loans to 38 countries (17 of them HIPCs) were classified according to their ownership and their program outcome. Statistical analysis indeed confirmed a significant relationship between program ownership and program outcome. Almost half the programs, however, were classified as having low or very low degrees of ownership.
24Also related to this argument is the hypothesis of the catalytic effect of debt relief advanced by Cline (1995). According to this hypothesis, the willingness of creditors to offer explicit debt reduction allows policymakers in the indebted country to claim that “we have succeeded in putting the debt problems behind us,” thereby increasing both domestic support for economic reform and future willingness to pay.
25A selection of these studies includes Borensztein (1990b), Cohen (1993, 1995), Greene and Villanueva (1991), Hadjimichael and others (1995), Jenkins (1995), Oshikoya (1994), Serven and Solimano (1991), Warner (1994), Savvides (1992), and Mlambo and Mhlophe (1995). Cohen (1993) and Savvides (1992) use a large sample of developing countries that includes most HIPCs, and Cohen (1995), Oshikoya (1994), and Hadjimichael and others (1995) focus on sub-Saharan Africa, where most HIPCs are located.

    Other Resources Citing This Publication